Asian Countries as Capital Exporters: Studies of Prospective International Capital Ownership Patterns Across the Pacific at the Turn of the Century INTRODUCTION
In 1988, the current account surplus of Japan was
and about 2.8 percent of its GNP. On the other hand, the current account
2.8 percent of its GNP. The bilateral current account surplus of the
Japan had accumulated net assets equal to 292 bi11ion dollars (10.2
of its GNP), and the U.S. accumulated net liability equal to 532.5
of its GNP). These figures, along with their
historical trends, clearly indicate that Japan is emerging as one of
the major capital exporting countries and that the United States is
shifting its position from capital exporter to capital importer.
In the meantime, Taiwan is also transforming itself into a
capital exporter (the current account surplus of Taiwan was
or more than 8 percent of its GNP; the level of foreign reserves at
) We also expect that Korea will become a major capital
exporter if it follows the pattern of Japan’s economic development in
this respect as it has followed it in many other respects.
The purpose of this study is to explain these trends in the current
account and the accompanying capital movements by utilizing a growth
theoretic frame work, and to predict probable patterns of
international credit-debt of major countries in the future.
The changing international credit-debt structure depends on the
path of net excess savings over investment, which in turn depends on
people’s consumption choice over time. In a world where capital
movements are becoming more and more liberalized, what are the long-run
consequences of cross-country differences in the saving ratio
(1966a) applied neoclassical growth theory to this problem and derived
a simple formula for the asymptotic debt-capital ratio of the country
with the relatively smaller propensity to save in the world economy
where capital moves freely. He also put forward a hypothesis on the
determinants of capital movements that was tested on U.S.-Canadian data.
This apparatus has also been applied to the recent large trade surplus
(capital export) of Japan to the United States in Hamada and Iwata (1985).
Here it was shown that after the deregulation of Japanese capital
controls in 1980, capital movements took on similar patteins to those
predicted by theoretical model. This exercise also bears a strong
similarity to the analysis of inter-sectoral factor movements which
was explored by Fei and Ranis (1964), and already applied to the Pacific
Area (Fei, Ohkawa and Ranis, 1985). In this study we have attempted
to extend this exercise to see how this growth the oretic approach can
explain the past pattern of capital movements among countries on the
globe. In order to analyze properly the determinants of capital
movements and to forecast future capital ownership patterns, however,
we must identify the historical trends in international capital
movements in the past and the current state of the net capital flows
as well as current credit-liability patterns. In order to diagnose and
possibly to prescribe policy actions, one has to have the an atomy of
the current situation. Accordingly, we have to construct a
flow-of-funds table, both in terms of flows and outstanding stocks at
the global level. This is a challenging task, but at the same time,
an extremely difficult task. Difficulties stem from the un
availability of the data, differences in statistical definitions
between countries, ever-changing exchange rates, and from the
politically sensitive nature of some of the data which impels
governments and private institutions to restrict disseminations even
Chapter 1 is the first step in constructing a consistent
estimation of the world credit-debt structure in the past and present.
We attempt to provide a global perspective on international capital
ownership patterns. In Chapter 1 we had to be satisfied with a very
rough bird’s-eye approximation of the regional components of the
credit-debt structure among those countries like the United States,
Japan, Germany, and the United Kingdom, where substantial data are
After presenting a brief overview of the current account
structure in the 1980s, we construct the world asset- and debt-matrix
and examine its characteristics. Also, we derive the total and regional
decomposition of the net asset-debt position of the United States, Japan
and Germany; and by comparing them with the accumulated current account
balances, we seek the relationship between the current account and the
flow of funds captured by the net change of the external position. Also,
we examine the regional decomposition of the foreign direct investment
and portfolio investment of the United States and Japan.
A striking result found in this paper is that though during the
seven years between 1980 to 1987 Japan recorded a large current account
surplus of 254 billion dollars vis-a-vis the United States, most of
the flow of funds went, however, through EC in such a way that the United
States increased its liability to EC by 323 billion dollars while it
increased its liability to Japan only by 82 billion dollars.
The re-evaluation problem can be a source of this discrepancy
between the accumulated balance of payments and the change in the net
credit position. The main reason for this discrepancy, however, could
be explained as fo1lows: Suppose the payments of trade transactions
between two countries are made through the third country, and
international investments are also made in the same manner. Suppose
a Japanese company exports goods to the United States and transfers
the payment to its account in a British bank in London. Then, in the
Japanese current account statistics, this transaction is recorded as
an export to the United States; in the U.S. balance of payments as an
import from Japan. In the capital account, however, it will be recorded
as an increase in the net position of Japan towards the United Kingdom
as well as a reduction in the net position of Unite States towards the
This observation indicates the necessity of a comprehensive
framework to analyze the global movements of capital. The profession
already has theories of direct investments often based on methods of
industrial organization and sometimes based on the microeconomic
analysis of the foreign investment incentives to circumvent the
protection effects of import tariffs and quotas; it has the theory of
portfolio investment based on the international generalization of the
capital market theory; also, the theory of short-term capital flows
depending on the interest parity; finally, we have the theory of
financial intermediation that explains layers of credit and liabilities
consistent with the analysis of the savings investment conducted in
this study. However, there seems to be hardly any comprehensive
framework that integrates these theories of capital movements with the
macroeconomic savings investment gap. In order to explain the
international financial intermediation observed in this chapter, we
have to develop an international theory of financial intermediation.
This gives us an important but formidable task, which we hope to pursue
Chapter 2 represents an extension of Chapter 1 and introduces
data useful for constructing regional world asset and debt matrices
for the two interesting parts of the world, the Asian New Industrializing
Economies (NIEs) and the Heavily Indebted Latin American Countries
(HILACs). Despite the lack of complete data for the regional
distribution of external assets and debt, Chapter 2 gathers important
data that are sufficient to draw a number of interesting conclusions.
In part I of Chapter 2, we study the NIEs that are emerging as
crucial countries in international capital movements in the Asian
region. Taiwan and perhaps Korea are becoming major capital exporters,
while Hong Kong and Singapore are now playing indisputably crucial roles
as international financial centers. More specifically, the total
external assets of Korea and Taiwan have grown tremendously in the 1980’s.
Korea has moved from being a large to a small net debtor country, while
Taiwan has become a large net asset country. Korea and Taiwan, under
the government control. Accumulated most of their external assets in
the form of foreign exchange reserves, but we expect an increase in
foreign direct and portfolio investment by Korea and Taiwan in the
Foreign direct investment has become a significant source of
capital for Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore. While the absolute amount
of FDI entering Korea is significant, it nevertheless is small relative
to the Korean borrowing from foreign creditors. Hong Kong and Singapore
have become crucial financial intermediaries in the Asian region.
Singapore’s ACU has grown remarkably over the course of the 1980’s;
Hong Kong’s offshore banking center quickly caught up with Singapore
in size after the creation of the Tokyo Offshore Market by Japan in
Behind the scene, de-regulation and liberalization of
international capital flows are in progress in the Asian region. For
example, the growth of NIE securities markets, increasing access by
foreigners to the Korean stock exchange, loosening of regulations on
foreign direct investment, less government control on foreign currency
holdings in Korea and Taiwan, and the creation of the TOM (Tokyo Offshore
Market) by Japan are all examples of this important trend.
, we focus on the thirteen most indebted countries of
Chile, Columbia, Costa Rica, Ecuador, Honduras, Mexico, Nicaragua, Peru,
Uruguay, and Venezuela. On the HILACs’ debt side, we find that their
dependence on the U.S. has increased, especially to private creditors,
while EEC lending to the them declined substantially, especially from
private sources. Japanese lending to these countries increased during
the 1980’s but remains small relative to the U.S.
On the HILACs’ asset side we find that they have shown an
increasingly strong preference for placing their assets in U.S. banks
as opposed to U. K. and West German banks. The external assets of the
HILACs have increased at a significant rate over the 1980’s, strongly
suggesting that capital flight remains a significant problem in the
Regarding foreign direct investment we find that FDI has been
an important source of capital for the HILACs, but that this source
has declined substantially relative to the debt over the course of the
debt crisis and its aftermath. The most significant feature of the debt
problems of the HILACs is the growing financial interconnection between
the HILACs and both the public and private sector of the United States.
The U.S. has become inextricably intertwined with the Latin American
debt dilemma. While, on the face of it, stratagems like debt conversion
and greater lending by the IMF, the World Bank, and the Japanese
government are important steps towards alleviating the debt problems
of the HILACs, it is important to consider as well the destabilizing
effects of this third party intervention on the willingness of both
the U. S. and the HILACs to continue to compromise on the debt problem.
Chapter 3 studies the trends of current accounts and accompanying
capital movements from a growth-theoretic perspective and attempts to
predict the credit-debt structure among major industrialized countries
(the United States, Japan and West Germany), at the turn of the
twenty-first century. The past movements of national savings and
investment may support the “habitat” view by Feldstein and Horioka that
the supply of savings create investment where it is generated. Rapid
increases in the United States foreign debt would imply, however, the
relevance of the “traditional” view that capital moves so as to equate
its rates of return. The difference in saving ratios among countries
could lead to a serious consequence. The simulation exercises show that
the ratio of external debt to capital stock in the United States will
over the long run in the absence of the recovery of its
savings ratio to the historical standard of the 1970s.
The U.S. and Japan moves toward significant reduction in external
imbalance after 1988. Now the current account surplus
two countries in term of GNP reached at about 2
the bilateral U.S.-Japan current account balance still remains large
and unchanged from 1988. It is likely to register about
which constitutes one of the factors to intensify trade friction between
In view of these facts, Chapter 4 follows up Chapter 3 in studying
the underlying trend of sustained bilateral imbalance between the U.S.
and Japan. In Chapter 3 there remained a significant gap between
theoretical estimates based on the model and actual development of
bilateral current account imbalance. Theoretical values tend to
overestimate the actual trend notably with respect to U.S.-Japan
bilateral external imbalance, while the gap is smaller in the case of
U.S.-Germany imbalance. Chapter 4 shows that the intensive use of land
as well as land price hike in Japan in the 1980s may affect the external
After reviewing the gap on U.S.-Japan bilateral imbalance
between the model estimate and actual imbalance, Chapter 4 assesses
the role of the land and land price rise as one of the determinants
of external imbalance. It is shown that the land price hike tends to
diminish the net capital outflow from Japan to the U.S. The policy
measures to contain the land price rise in Japan may give rise to enlarged
external surplus. On the other hand, the U. S. can reduce the net capital
inflow by strengthening policy measures to reduce the land price rise.
The higher land-capital stock ratio in Japan reduces the
equilibrium borrowing-capital stock ratio of the U.S. Moreover,
Chapter 4 has the following interesting policy implications. Higher
tax on land rent in the U. S. may lead to lower borrowing ratio, while
it increases the net lending ratio in Japan through the decline in real
land price and land-capital stock ratio. This result is in sharp
contrast to the view that the land price decline in Japan may decrease
the current account surplus through increased housing investment. In
our model, capital accumulation is enhanced by less attractive rate
of return on land (crowding-in). But the resulting lower land-capital
stock ratio leads to higher lending ratio of creditor country.
Conversely, the higher land-capital stock ratio in Japan works to reduce
both the short-run net borrowing of the U.S. to Japan and the long-run
The dependence of the time preference rate on the income level
of a country provides us with a significant implication in the
understanding of the dynamic relationship between savings behavior and
the pattern of economic development. Personal savings are the main
source of supply of capital. They are channeled through financial
markets to firms and used for capital accumulation. New investment
expands the production capacity embodying high productivity. More
output is produced with more efficient technology, generating more
income. When the time preference rate hinges on the income level,
higher levels of income will affect the time preference rate and hence
the consumption-savings pattern. If the intertemporal consumption
tilts toward the future, as is suggested by Fisher, more savings will
be available for capital accumulation and economic growth might be
accelerated. On the other hand, if consumers prefer present
consumption to that in the future, as is suggested by Uzawa, the speed
of economic growth will slow down. Chapter 5 studies the implication
of the time-preference schedule for the growing world economy.
Conventionally, economic growth theory was based on the
assumption of a constant rate of time preference. Uzawa and Obstfeld
introduced the rate of time preference that increases with the utility
level. Irving Fisher (The Theory of Interest) has a different opinion,
however, that people are more time impatient at the lower level of
Chapter 5 assumes a non-monotonic time preference schedule such
that people are more patient at the middle income levels and are less
Patient when they are either very poor or rich. Based on a nonlinear
savings function out of wealth implied by such a time-preference
schedule, this chapter develops a single-good, multi-country growth
model of a global economy with free capital mobility. The long-run
property of this system is characterized by three kinds of long-run
equilibrium: the starvation (fatal attractor) equilibrium, the
imperialism equilibria dominated by a nation or by a group of nations,
and the co-prosperity equilibrium where the wealth and the income of
countries in the system grow proportionately. Bifurcation phenomena
and the global stability of the system by the Lyapunov function will
Our system has a strong resemblance to some models of ecology
where species compete for their survival(May, Stability and Complexity
. Here we can properly analyze the transition of
a debt or to a creditor country from a global perspective, and
Thus, time preference rate is one of the key variables in
intertemporal pattern of consumption, even though
constancy of the time preference rate has been assumed traditionally
as constant in most of the literature on this issue. Chapter 6 examines
empirically the validity of the constancy hypothesis of the time
preference schedule, or the relationship between time preference and
economic development. There are three alternatives: Irving Fisher’s
hypothesis that the time preference rate is a decreasing function of
the income level; Uzawa’s hypothesis that the time preference rate is
an increasing function of consumption or income level; the last
hypothesis used in Chapter 5 is a combination of Fisher’s and Uzawa’s
hypothesis that suggests at the existence of a turning point in the
time preference. Using postwar annual time series data on consumption
in several countries, Chapter 6 tests the constant time preference
hypothesis. When the constant hypothesis is not supported by the data,
we further investigate statistically whether the time preference
schedule is well represented by Fisher’s hypothesis or by Uzawa’s or
by their combination. The countries covered by our study are Taiwan,
Korea, Japan, Germany and the U.S.A. The first four countries are
well-known for their high personal saving rates, while the saving rate
of the U. S. A. has been notably low. Moreover, the three countries
in the Far East have enjoyed high economic growth in the post-war period.
To sum up the results, the constant time preference hypothesis
is valid only for Korea and Germany. For Japan and Taiwan, the combined
hypothesis is appropriate. For the U. S. A., the Fisherian hypothesis
is supported by the data. Interestingly, the turning point in the
time-preference schedule roughly coincides with the period when high
income growth switches to low income growth.
Needless to say, our research still has some difficulties and
problems. In particular, in order to apply our framework to current
policy issues, we have to be very careful not to neglect the important
factors that may play crucial roles in the issues under consideration.
Brief, but pertinent, comments by Willem H. Buiter, John C. H. Feiand
T. N. Srinivasan clearly point out limitations and imperfections of
interpret those comments as the indication of the fact that a wide
research potential is open in the direction we are proceeding.
The Model Formulation Count what is countable, measure what is measurable, and what is not measurable, make measurable. 4.1 The Overall Process In using any kind of analytical or modeling approach for attacking a problem, there are five major steps:1) Understanding the real problem. 2) Formulating a model of the problem. 3) Gathering and generating the input data for the model (e.g., pe
MEDIA RELEASE KLM Royal Dutch Airlines marks its 80th Anniversary in Singapore with a myriad of celebrations [Singapore, 10 April 2013] – Commemorating 80 years of scheduled flights to Singapore, KLM today announced it will celebrate this spectacular milestone, with a myriad of events and campaigns for its customers. Mr Domingo De Cola, General Manager – Singapore,